Prague Economic Papers 2012, 21(3):291-308 | DOI: 10.18267/j.pep.425

The Weber-Fechner Law and Public Expenditures Impact to the Win-Margins at Parliamentary Elections

Paulo Jorge Reis Mourao
Economics & Management School, University of Minho, 4700 Braga - Portugal (paulom@eeg.uminho.pt).

This paper discusses the electoral implications of psychological motivation on voting functions. We tested a claim of the Weber-Fechner law as applied to electoral behaviour - specifically, that an expanded public sector leads politicians to make more significant, opportunistic distortions of public expenditures than the distortions observed when the public sector is diminished. We employed a system of simultaneous equations to test this hypothesis for cases observed in more than sixty democracies since 1960. We gave a special focus to the cases of Central and Eastern European countries. Our results confirm the main implications of the Weber-Fechner law. Years in incumbency, running for re-election, higher unemployment and higher inflation rates tend to generate negative moods, feelings and affects in the electorate; thus, these factors tend to approximate the vote share of the most voted party to the remaining vote share of the challenger political forces.

Keywords: voting, Central and Eastern European economies, Weber-Fechner law
JEL classification: D03, D72, P20

Published: January 1, 2012  Show citation

ACS AIP APA ASA Harvard Chicago IEEE ISO690 MLA NLM Turabian Vancouver
Mourao, P.J.R. (2012). The Weber-Fechner Law and Public Expenditures Impact to the Win-Margins at Parliamentary Elections. Prague Economic Papers21(3), 291-308. doi: 10.18267/j.pep.425
Download citation

References

  1. Aidt, T., Veiga, F., Veiga, L. (2010), "Election Results and Opportunistic Policies: A New Test of the Rational Political Business Cycle Model." Public Choice. Forthcoming. DOI 10.1007/s11127-010-9644-3. Go to original source...
  2. Akhmedov, A., Zhuravskaya, E. (2004), "Opportunistic Political Cycles: Test in a Young Democracy Setting." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119, No. 4, pp. 1301-38. Go to original source...
  3. Alt, J., Lassen, D. (2006), "Fiscal Transparency, Political Parties, and Debt In OECD Countries." European Economic Review 50, No. 6, pp. 1403-39. Go to original source...
  4. Barro, R., Lee, J. (2000), "International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications." Manuscript, Harvard University. Go to original source...
  5. Bellany, I. (1973), "The Problems of Balancing Reductions in Conventional Forces." The Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 17, No. 4 (Dec. 1973), pp. 657-671. Go to original source...
  6. Bernoulli, D. (1738), Specimen theoriae novae de mensura sortis. Commentarii Academiae Scientiarum Imperialis Petropolitanae. 5. Ed., pp. 175-192.
  7. Brader, T. (2006), Campaigning for Hearts and Minds: How Emotional Appeals in Political Ads Work. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Go to original source...
  8. Brandstätter, E., Brandstätter, H. (1996), "What's Money Worth? Determinants of the Subjective Value of Money." Journal of Economic Psychology. Vol. 17, pp. 443-464 Go to original source...
  9. Brender, A., Drazen, A. (2004), "Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies." NBER Working Papers Series 10539, 2004. (http://www.econ.umd.edu/~drazen/Data_Sets/Data_Sets.html). Go to original source...
  10. Brender, A., Drazen, A. (2007), "Electoral Fiscal Policy in New, Old, and Fragile Democracies." Comparative Economic Studies Vol. 49, No. 3, pp. 446-66. Go to original source...
  11. Brug, W., C. Eijk, Franklin, M. (2007), The Economy and the Vote: Economic Conditions and Elections in Fifteen Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007. Go to original source...
  12. Caplan, B. (2007), The Myth of the Rational Voter. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007.
  13. Chote, R., C. Emmerson, Tetlow, G. (2008), "The UK Public Finances: Ready for Recession?" The Institute for Fiscal Studies, IFS Briefing Note 79 (2008).
  14. Coates, D. (2004), "Additional Incumbent Spending Really Can Harm (at least some) Incumbents: An Analysis of Vote Share Maximization". Public Choice Vol. 95, pp. 63-87. Go to original source...
  15. Conover, P. (1981), "Political Cues and the Perception of Candidates". American Politics Quarterly, Vol. 9, pp. 427-448. Go to original source...
  16. DPI (2008), Database of Political Institutions. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2008.
  17. Edelman, M. (2001), The Politics of Misinformation: Communication, Society and Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001. Go to original source...
  18. Fechner, G. (1860), Elemente der Psychophysik. Lepzig: Breitkopf und Härtel, (reprint Amsterdam: Bonset, 1964).
  19. Hibbs, D. (1977), "Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy." American Political Science Review, Vol. 71, pp. 1467-87. Go to original source...
  20. Hibbs, D. (1987), The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1987. Go to original source...
  21. Hsiao, C. (2002), Analysis of Panel Data. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.
  22. IFS (2006), International Financial Statistics. New York: International Monetary Fund, 2006.
  23. Kates, S. (2004), "A Qualitative Exploration into Voters' Ethical Perceptions of Political Advertising: Discourse, Disinformation, and Moral Boundaries" Journal of Business Ethics, Vol. 17, pp. 1871-85. Go to original source...
  24. Kinder, D., Kiewiet, D. (1981), "Sociotropic Politics: The American Case." British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 11, pp. 129-61. Go to original source...
  25. Kramer, G. (1983), "The Ecological Fallacy Revisited: Aggregate Versus Individual-level Findings on Economics and Elections, and Sociotropic Voting." American Political Science Review, Vol. 77, pp. 92-111. Go to original source...
  26. Lewis-Beck, M., Norpoth, H., Weisberg, H., Jacoby, W. (2008), The American Voter Revisited. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press, 2008. Go to original source...
  27. Marcus, G. (1988), "The Structure of Emotional Response: 1984 Presidential Candidates." American Political Science Review, Vol. 82. pp. 737-62. Go to original source...
  28. Marcus, G., Neuman, R., MacKuen, M. (2000), Affective Intelligence and Political Judgement. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2000.
  29. Masin, S., Zudini, V., Antonelli, M. (2009), "Early Alternative Derivations of Fechner's Law". Journal of the History of the Behavioral Sciences, Vol. 45, No. 1, pp. 56-65. Go to original source...
  30. Nannestad, P., Paldam, M. (1994),"The VP-Function: A Survey of the Literature on Vote and Popularity Functions after 25 Years." Public Choice, Vol. 79, No. 3-4, pp. 213-45. Go to original source...
  31. Niskanen, W. (1998), "A Vote for Perot Was a Vote for the Status Quo." Cato Journal, Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 85-91.
  32. Nordhaus, W. (1975), "The Political Business Cycle." Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 42, pp. 169-90. Go to original source...
  33. Puviani, A. (1903), Teoria della illusione finanziaria, Palermo: Sandron, 1903.
  34. Shi, M., Svensson, J. (2006), "Political Budget Cycles: Do They Differ across Countries and Why?" Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 90, pp.1367-89. Go to original source...
  35. Shi, M., Svensson, J. (2002), "Political Budget Cycles in Developed and Developing Countries." Manuscript, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University, 2002.
  36. Shoemaker, P., Reese, S. (1991), Mediating the Message. Theories of Influence on Mass Media Contents. New York, London: Longman, 1991.
  37. Sinn, H. (2003), "Weber's Law and the Biological Evolution of Risk Preferences: The Selective Dominance of the Logarithmic Utility Function, 2002 Geneva Risk Lecture." The GENEVA Papers on Risk and Insurance - Theory; Vol. 28, No. 2, pp. 87-100. Go to original source...
  38. Skouras, T., Avlonitis, G., Indounas, K. (2005), "Economics and Marketing on Pricing: How and Why Do They Differ?" Journal of Product & Brand Management, Vol. 14, No. 6, pp. 362-374. Go to original source...
  39. Stevens, S. (1962). "The Surprising Simplicity of Sensory Metrics," American Psychologist, Vol 17, No. 1, pp. 17, 29-39. Go to original source...
  40. Stevens, S. (1975), Psychophysics: Introduction to its Perceptual, Neural and Social Prospects. New York: Wiley, 1975. Go to original source...
  41. Stimson, J. (1999), Public Opinion in America: Moods, Cycles, and Swings. Boulder: Westview Press, 1999.
  42. Tufte, E. (1978), Political Control of the Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978. Go to original source...
  43. Von Mises, M. (1949), Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1949.
  44. Weber, E. (1834), De pulsu, resorptione, auditu et tactu. Annotationes anatomicae et physiologicae. Leipzig: Koehler, 1834.
  45. Wooldridge, J. (200), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2002.
  46. Zafirovski, M. (2001), "Max Weber's Analysis of Marginal Utility Theory and Psychology Revisited: Latent Propositions in Economic Sociology and the Sociology of Economics." History of Political Economy, Vol. 33, No. 3; pp. 437-458. Go to original source...

This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License (CC BY NC ND 4.0), which permits non-comercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original publication is properly cited. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.